페이지 이미지
PDF
ePub

one of the penalties of life in society. He does not avoid his predicament by killing.

This reasoning is not true, I admit, in the case of the borderruffian, who walks about the earth with one hand on his hip-pocket, and shoots each similar gentleman at sight, he would never regret that he had killed his man. But the argument itself is inapplicable. To talk of dishonor and cowardice in the case of such a cowardly and bullying brute is a bit inopportune.

But, after all, such feelings as I have described are merely the natural uncontrolled impulses of the individual; and it is to control such feelings, both forcibly and by putting an end to the necessity for their exercise, that law itself exists. The duel, war, and lynching show the unnecessary failure of law; so does the doctrine of Runyan v. State. If the law is to be carried out it must protect the state against such homicides. The interests of the state alone are to be regarded in justifying crime; and those interests require that one man should live rather than that another should stand his ground in a private conflict.

Joseph H. Beale, Fr.

HARVARD LAW REVIEW.

Published monthly, during the Academic Year, by Harvard Law Students.

[merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]
[ocr errors]

THE IMPORTANCE OF THE MERGER DECISION. The industrial reorganization during the ten years last past may be set down as making the most important epoch in the economic history of the United States. In consequence of the stress of the situation, the law governing consolidation has been put to the test as never before. The ultimate inquiry has been as to the underlying public policy, which must always be the criterion when any question of law touches the issues of life so nearly. Once in a while, with the more emphasis because of its infrequency, the great truth is shown again that whenever there is an accepted belief among men that a certain policy is their social salvation, that belief has already become a principle of law. The decision in the United States v. The Northern Securities Company et al., 120 Fed. Rep. 721, is untechnical, therefore, because it has the unreason of a policy that is believed by most to be indispensable.

When the recent movement is described as the reorganization of the industrial system, it is recognized that the change has been from one unit to another unit. The exact description is that the advance has been from a limited number of corporations into a consolidation of them. Such consolidation in the face of an adverse policy which made against combination has been an almost desperate forward movement. There have been four attempts: First, the poola direct agreement between the corporations for their joint operation, Addystone Pipe Co. v. U. S., 175 U. S. 211; second, the trust an indirect arrangement between the shareholders to direct the action of their corporations, State v. Standard Oil Co., 49 Oh. St. 137; third, the holding corporation a central corporation to own the shares of the constituent companies, Compress Co. v. Compress Co., 70 Miss. 669; fourth,

the single corporation-which bought the properties of the former corporations outright, Richardson v. Buhl, 77 Mich. 632. The state of the law at the present writing is that the first and second of these, since they are without central incorporation, are within the plain rule against combination in restraint of trade; while the third and fourth, even though they have central incorporation, are under the same suspicion.

From step to step in this succession there is an evolution towards integration. Indeed the necessity of rapid organization upon the basis of unity was obvious if the law against combination was to be avoided. What makes the holding as to the organization of this Northern Securities Company of much less importance is that the process of integration had gone but half the way. There was a central corporation; but the constituent corporations were left in existence. Long before this new decision it had been recognized that the scheme of the holding company might be illegal as leaving in existence a combination in restraint of trade. People v. Chicago Gas Trust Co., 130 Ill. 268; Pearsall v. No. Pacific Co., 161 U. S. 646. The legality of the organization of a great industrial company upon the basis of a new incorporation is the crucial question at the present moment. The permanent interest in the Northern Securities Case must be the bearing of it upon the ultimate holding as to the legality of this final form of consolidation a central corporation in which the constituent companies go out of existence. In truth, these last two forms are very different.

So far had the law gone that at the time of the organization of the Northern Securities Company one might have predicted that it would be obnoxious to established principles if the court applied those principles in a broad way to get at the substance of the matter rather than at the forms employed. The obvious fact was that two great railroad systems had entered into a combination in suppression of competition. It was true that in form these constituent companies were not parties to the combination. The court refused to be stopped by such a fiction. That is the portentous thing -this attitude of the court. This decision against the scheme of the holding company is a decision against a combination in fact, that is all. The present form of organization of the great industrial companies is, therefore, not touched by this decision, for the single corporation is not a combination. Trenton Potteries Co. v. Oliphant, 58 N. J. Eq. 507; Oakdale Mfg. Co. v. Garst, 18 R. I. 484. So long as incorporation is permitted to a small enterprise, it must be permitted to a large enterprise. Any danger there may seem to be in this Northern Securities decision is not in the decision itself, but in the possibility of an extension of it.

B. W.

CONSTITUTIONALITY OF MUNICIPAL FUEL PLANTS. — Aroused by the recent scarcity of fuel, the legislature of Massachusetts has again consulted the Supreme Court of the state as to the constitutionality of proposed legislation authorizing cities and towns to establish and operate municipal coal yards. In re Municipal Fuel Plants, 66 N. E. Rep. 25; cf. Opinions of the Justices, 155 Mass. 598; see 6 HARV. L. REV. 100. On the previous occasion five of the justices declared that such a law would be unconstitutional, on the ground that buying and selling fuel is not a public use for which taxation can be authorized, and also that it is not a legitimate governmental function. Mr. Justice Holmes, however, dissented on both points, and Mr. Justice Barker gave a qualified dissent. The present justices,

though adhering in the main to the principles formerly expressed, practically take the position of Mr. Justice Barker. In certain emergencies, they say, the government alone might be able to obtain fuel, and might then constitutionally buy and sell for the relief of the community. Mr. Justice Loring refuses to join in this qualification of the former opinion. The view taken by Mr. Justice Holmes has now no advocate on the bench.

See

The admission by the court that under the circumstances described municipalities might establish coal yards seems of little practical importance. Such a situation would rarely occur and would of necessity be very temporary; indeed, Mr. Justice Loring thinks it impossible. The main significance of the opinion lies in the continued and vigorous opposition of the court to radical extension of the doctrine of municipal ownership. The growing popularity of that doctrine has been attested by recent municipal elections. The extent to which popular feeling, if uncontrolled by the courts, is likely to carry it is shown by the experience of British cities. The corporation of Glasgow now owns and in many instances operates not only gas and water plants and street railways, but also scores of ordinary businesses, such as laundries and retail stores. Whether the courts may restrain and overrule the legislature in this matter, and, if they may, where they will draw the line, are therefore questions of great and increasing importance. The legal question presented obviously is not whether such a change in our theory of the state is advisable, but whether it is constitutional. That the courts will hold it unconstitutional for a state to enter into ordinary private callings seems sure. It is probable that they will lay down some such test as "virtual monopoly," permanent control of the supply or service. 16 HARV. L. REV. 73; cf. State v. City of Toledo, 48 Oh. St. 112. When a business supplying a general public need is of such a nature that a substantial monopoly is necessary or inevitable either from economic reasons or because required by the public welfare, then the state may regulate it and even engage in it. But it cannot spend the public money in operating private industries that may be well left to the regulation of competition. Under the test suggested the mining of coal might be considered a public calling, but the retail selling could not be so held. Monopolistic combinations of coal dealers, however, while not economically necessary may be so easily formed and maintained because of the absolute control of the supply by a few men that the business might be distinguished from the sale of ordinary articles. But the actual situation does not seem to warrant such a dangerous extension of the class of public callings. If the mine operators should extend their control over the entire distribution of the coal, control of the retail selling by municipalities might be considered constitutional but would be of little benefit. If the state of Pennsylvania acquired and operated the coal mines, there would be no reason why Massachusetts or its municipalities should control the distribution. It should be noticed that the court in the principal case is not rendering a decision, but is merely giving an advisory opinion. It might be more reluctant to hold actual legislation unconstitutional, but there is nothing to indicate that it would withdraw from its present position.

The

INTERESTED DIRECTOR'S RIGHT TO VOTE AS STOCKHOLDER. validity of the recent $200,000,000 loan to the United States Steel Corporation has again been contested, this time on the ground that the private

interest of certain directors barred their votes as stockholders. A tentative agreement for the loan from the Morgan Company was negotiated by the directors of the Steel Corporation and submitted to its stockholders. Several of these directors were members of the Morgan Company and of the syndicate which was to act as surety in the transaction, and it was conceded that without the votes on the shares controlled by such directors the necessary two-thirds vote for validating the agreement would not have been obtained. The court, in sustaining the transaction, appears to rest its argument solely upon the general proposition that in the absence of fraud private interest is no bar to a stockholder's right to vote. Hodge v. U. S. Steel Corp., 54 Atl. Rep. 1 (N. J., C. A.) Another general rule of law, however, declares that when directors act as directors they cannot make a binding contract in which one of their number has a private interest. Irrespective of actual fraud, such a contract is voidable by seasonable action on the part of the corporation. Pearson v. Concord R. R. Co., 62 N. H. 537. See 15 HARV. L. REV. 672. The question is therefore raised whether these two rules become inconsistent when, as in the principal case, a stockholder is also a director; and if so, which rule should be modified?

A consideration of the facts of two leading cases upon the subject shows conclusively that the rules are in substance conflicting. See Beatty v. N. W. Transport Co., L. R. 12 App. Cas. 589; Bjorngaarrd v. Goodhue County Bank, 49 Minn. 483. In each case the corporation was considering the ratification of an existing though voidable contract made by interested directors, who, as a matter of fact, possessed a majority of the stock. To allow directors to vote under such circumstances is evidently to make ratification inevitable, and thus to deprive the transaction of any actual voidability. Yet the court allowed their votes under the general rule that interest is no bar to a stockholder's vote. By thus applying this rule the court completely nullified the effect of the other general rule which declares that contracts made by interested directors should be voidable. The latter rule seems to demand an entirely disinterested vote by the corporation on the question of ratification, and hence whenever an interested director is allowed to vote in the stockholders' meeting a modification of this rule results.

Granting, then, that the two rules may come into conflict, it is to be noted that the decisions cited represent the weight of authority and agree with the principal case in asserting that whatever be its effect upon other rules, the rule which declares interest no bar to the stockholder's vote is to remain unmodified. Strong reasons exist, however, for doubting the soundness of this view. The rule as to voidability of directors' contracts is highly salutary and should be made effective. It gives the corporation a free hand in discarding questionable transactions; whereas the prevailing view would frequently necessitate proof of actual fraud. This burden would rest heavily upon an objecting stockholder, since he lacks the intimate knowledge of corporate affairs possessed by a director. On the other hand, if the director's interest were made a bar to his right to vote as shareholder, no radical change in the general rule as to the stockholders' right to vote would result. The latter rule is based upon the inexpediency of entering upon an investigation as to the private interests of a great number of stockholders in order to determine the validity of corporate transactions. Under the change proposed, however, though some investigation would be necessary, it would be limited to the interests of directors, a very narrow class of persons.

It would thus seem that a director's interest should be made an exception to the general rule that interest is never a bar to a stockholder's vote.

« 이전계속 »