페이지 이미지
PDF
ePub

When the specific charges of a railway company have been so adjusted that each is reasonable, as measured by the service performed, and when that company abstains from any undue discrimination in charges or service between individuals, localities, or commodities, if, by reason of the poor location of the railway, high cost of construction, faulty management, or any other cause, the revenues derived from all of its charges are so small as to yield no net return on its capitalization, that is the misfortune of its owners. On the other hand, if by reason of the favorable location of the road, low cost of construction, efficiency of management, or any other cause, the net return to the owners of the property is substantial, that is their good fortune. They are entitled to the use and enjoyment of the whole of such net returns in the same measure as the farmer whose land is fertile and is favorably located is entitled to the use and enjoyment of all that he can make out of his farm by the most efficient management.

While it was not a case involving railway rates, I believe that the views announced by Justice Brewer of the Supreme Court, in Cotting v. Kansas City Stock Yards Company, lay down, in clear and unmistakable language, the rule which should be applied to the determination of the reasonableness of any railway charge. Speaking of a person who has devoted his property to a public use, Justice Brewer said:

"The state's regulation of his charges is not to be measured by the aggregate of his profits, determined by the volume of business, but by the question whether any particular charge to an individual dealing with him is, considering the service rendered, an unreasonable exaction. In other words, if he has a thousand transactions a day and his charges in each are but a reasonable compensation for the benefit received by the party dealing with him, such charges do not become unreasonable because by reason of the multitude the aggregate of his profits is large. The question is not how much he makes out of his volume of business, but whether in each particular transaction the charge is an unreasonable exaction for the services rendered. He has a right to do business. He has a right to charge for each separate service that which is reasonable compensation therefor, and the legislature may not deny him such reasonable compensation, and may not interfere simply because out of the multitude of his transactions the amount of his profits is large."

In this case Justice Brewer clearly announces the rule which I believe should be applied to all questions affecting the reasonableness of railway charges. He clearly lays down the principle that the only question involved in the matter there under discussion was whether any particular charge for a specific service was an unreasonable exaction as measured by that service. He indicates that the value of the service to the person for whom it is rendered must be the principal factor in determining the reasonableness of the charge. This rule eliminates from consideration, except as I shall hereafter explain, all questions of capitalization and of the value or cost of the property used in performing the service by declaring explicitly that "the legislature may not deny him such reasonable compensation, and may not interfere simply because out of the multitude of his transactions the amount of his profits is large." The application of this rule to privately owned railways, which I believe to be proper and will ultimately be done, clearly denies to government the right to place any limitation on the amount that may be earned on railway capital. It would invite the people of the United States to invest their money in the great and honorable business of transportation with the assurance that the properties they create will have the equal protection of the laws and will be surrounded by the same safeguards as are thrown around property in other forms. It would encourage those engaged in this business to strive constantly to make their service more efficient by the adoption of improved appliances and methods with the assurance that they will be permitted to reap the profits of their enterprise and skill.

Further, in a time of advancing commodity prices and labor costs, the fact that the whole body of its transportation charges fails to yield a fair and reasonable return on the capital invested in a railway is presumptive evidence that there has been such an increase in the cost of the service and in the value of the service as to require a readjustment of charges upon a higher average level. This is but another way of saying that rates must be reasonable for, and under the conditions and circumstances of, the service. In the changed conditions growing out of higher prices for everything else a higher price for railway transportation becomes reasonable.

Under such conditions it is to the public interest that such a readjustment should take place, for the primary interest of the

public in the railways is in adequacy of facilities and efficiency of service, and these can be provided, in a country with a constantly increasing volume of traffic, only when the average return on capital invested in railways bears such a relation to the returns on investments in other forms of property as to insure a constant flow of new capital into railway enterprises. In other words, the fair maintenance of the just credit of the railways is a circumstance which should be taken into consideration in determining the reasonableness of rates, not only in the interest of the railways, but in the interest of the public. In this connection, I think we may properly refer to the relation of the governmental policy of Germany to the wonderful industrial development that has marked the recent history of that country and is still in progress. It is not without significance that we find the highest court in the German empire saying:

“When in a branch of industry the prices of a product fall too low, and the successful conduct of the industry is endangered or becomes impossible, the crisis which sets in is detrimental, not merely to individuals, but to society as a whole. It is in the interests of the community, therefore, that inordinately low prices should not exist in any industry for a long time.”

If this is true as to the prices of the products of any industry, I believe it is equally true of the charges of a railway, for transportation is a part of production, and, in our modern civilization, the prosperity of every industry and of every individual is affected, directly or indirectly, by transportation.

RETURN ON CAPITAL INVESTED IN
MANUFACTURES, AGRICULTURE
AND RAILROADS

BY L. E. JOHNSON,

President Norfolk & Western Railway Company.

FROM ADDRESS BEFORE THE VIRGINIA STATE FARMERS' INSTITUTE, ROANOKE, JANUARY 12, 1911.

The statistics showing the revenue derived from capital invested in manufactures, agriculture, and railroads in the United States are, for the fiscal year ended June 30, 1905, as follows:

[merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][ocr errors][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small][merged small]
[blocks in formation]

The above tables show the relation of the annual net return to each one thousand dollars of capital invested, as follows:

Manufactures

Agriculture

Railroads

.$151
98

44

To produce one dollar of net returns it required $6.62 of capital invested in manufactures, $9.44 of capital in the case of agriculture, and $22.40 of capital in the case of the railroads.

The average salary-wage paid workers in manufactures was $539 and by railroads $607, the average salary-wage paid by the railroads being 12.6 per cent. greater than the average paid in manufactures.

For every one thousand dollars of expediture, $245 was paid in salary-wage in manufactures and $572 was paid by the railroads.

That the high salary-wage for the railroads was not caused by the heavy salaries of the administrative officers is shown by the fact that of the $839,944,680 paid in 1905 by the railroads in salaries and wages, but $15,155,278, or 1.8 per cent., went to the general officers.

Of the total expeditures for manufactures, but 24 per cent. was for salary-wage, while of the total expenditure for the railroads, 57 per cent. was for salary-wage.

« 이전계속 »