페이지 이미지
PDF
ePub

time the bank has not suspended or failed, unless a contrary intention is manifested.

On the contrary, in Pennsylvania and some other states, as before stated, where a payment in bank bills is made in good faith their acceptance is not deemed to be upon the faith of any such guaranty, but is governed by the rule of caveat emptor, and the maxim of melior est conditio defendentis.1

1 In Bayard v. Shunk, 1 W. & S. 92, Gibson, C. J., expounds and enforces this view with great vigor of language and logic. He says: "Cases in which the bills and notes of a third party were transferred for a debt are not to the purpose; and most of those which have been cited are of that stamp. Where the parties to such a transaction are silent in respect to the terms of it, the rules of interpretation are few and simple. If the securities are transferred for a debt contracted at the time, the presumption is that they were received in satisfaction of it; but if for a precedent debt, it is that they are received as collateral security for it; and in either case it may be rebutted by direct or circumstantial evidence. But by the conventional rules of business, a transfer of bank notes, though they are of the same mould and obligation betwixt the original parties, is regulated by peculiar principles, and stands on a different footing. They are lent by the banks as cash; they are paid away as cash; and the language of Lord Mansfield in Miller v. Race, 1 Burr. 452, was not too strong when he said, they are treated as money, as cash, in the ordinary course and transaction of business by the general consent of mankind, which gives them the credit and currency of money to all intents and purposes; they are as much money as guineas themselves are, or any other coin that is used in

common payments is money or cash.' If such were their legal character in England, where there was but one bank, how emphatically must it be so here where they have supplanted coin for every purpose but that of small change, and where they have excluded it from circulation almost entirely. It is true, as was remarked in Young v. Adams, 6 Mass. 182, that our bank notes are private contracts without a public sanction like that which gives operation to the lawful money of the country; but it is also true that they pass for cash, both here and in England, not by force of any such sanction, but by the legislation of general consent, induced by their great convenience, if not the absolute necessities of mankind. Miller v. Race is a leading case which has never been doubted in England, or, except in a case presently to be noticed, in America; and it goes very far to rule the point before us; for if the wheel of commerce is to be stopped or turned backwards in order to repair accidents to it from impurities in the medium which keeps it in motion, except those which, few and far between, are occasioned by forgery, bank notes must cease to be a part of the currency, or the business of the world must stand still. The weight of authority bearing directly on the point is (1841) decisively in favor of the position that bona fide payment in the notes of a broken bank discharges the debt.

Where recourse is allowed to the party who paid out [367] the bills it does not depend on their being worthless. Parker, C. J., said: "The case of a payment in bills of a broken baňk cannot be distinguished in principle from a payment in coun

Camidge v. Allenby, 6 B. & C. 373; Scruggs v. Gass, 8 Yerg. 175; Young v. Adams, 6 Mass. 182; against Lightbody v. Ontario Bank, 11 Wend. 9; affirmed, 13 id. 101.

"To assume that the solvency of the bank at the time of the transfer is an inherent condition of it is to assume the whole ground of the argument. The conclusion concurred in by all, however, was that the medium must turn out to have been what the debtor offered it for at the time of payment. How does that consist with the equitable principle that there must be, in every case, a motive for the interference of the law, but that it must be stronger than any to be found on the other side; else the equity being equal, and the balance inclining to neither side, things must be left to stand as they are (Fonb. B. 1, ch. V, § 3; id. ch. IV, § 25); in other words, that the law interferes not to shift a loss from one innocent man to another equally innocent, and a stranger to the cause of it. The self-evident justice of this would be proof, were it necessary, that it is a principle of the common law. But we need go no further in search of authority for it than Miller v. Race, in which one who had received a stolen bank note for full consideration in the course of his business was not compelled to restore it. It was intimated in the Ontario Bank v. Lightbody that there was a preponderance of equity in that case, not on the side of him who had lost the note, but of him who had last given value for it. Why last? The maxim, prior in tempore potior in jure, prevails between prior and sub

sequent purchasers indifferently of a legal or an equitable title. It is for that reason the owner of a stolen horse can reclaim him of a purchaser from the thief; and were not the field of commerce market overt for everything which performs the office of money in it, the owner of a stolen note might follow it into the hands of a bona fide holder of it. But general convenience requires that he should not; and it was that principle, not any consideration of the equities betwixt the parties, which ruled the case of Miller v. Race. But a more forcible illustration of the principle, were the case indisputably law, might be had in Levy v. Bank of the United States, 4 Dall. 234; S. C., 1 Bin. 27, in which the placing even a forged check to the credit of a depositor as cash- a transaction really not within any principle of conventional law was held to conclude the bank; and to this may be added the entire range of cases in which the purchaser of an article from a dealer has been bound to bear a loss from a defect in the quality of it. And for the same reason that the law refuses to interfere between parties mutually innocent, it refuses to interfere between those who are mutually culpable; as in the case of an action for negligence. What is there, then, in the case before us to take it out of this great principle of the common law? The position taken by the courts of New York is that every one who parts with his property is entitled to expect the value of it in coin. Doubtless he is. He may exact payment in precious stones, if such is the bargain. But

[ocr errors]

terfeit money. From the time of the failure of the bank they cease to be the proper representatives of money, whether [368] they are at the time near to or at a distance from the bank. They may have a greater value than counterfeit bills,

where he has accepted without reserve what the conventional laws of the country declare to be cash, his claim to anything else is at an end. Bills of exchange and promissory notes enter not into the transactions of commerce as money; but it impresses even these with qualities which do not belong to ordinary securities. The holder of one of them, who has taken it in the ordinary course, can recover on it, whether there was a consideration between the original parties or not. . . . "The assertion that it is always an original and subsisting part of the agreement that a bank note shall turn out to have been good when it was paid away can be conceded no farther than regards its genuineness. That genuine notes are supposed to be equal to coin is disproved by daily experience, which shows that they circulate by the consent of whole communities at their nominal value when notoriously below it. But why hold the payer responsible for the failure of the bank only when it has been ascertained at the time of the payment, and not for insolvency ending in an ascertained failure afterwards? As the bank may have been actually insolvent before it closed to let the world know it, we must carry his responsibility back beyond the time when it ceased to redeem its notes, if we carry it back at all. Were it not for the conventional principle that the purchaser of a chattel takes it with its defects, the purchaser of a horse with the seeds of mortal disease in him might refuse to pay for him though his vigor and usefulness were yet unim

paired; and if we strip a payment in bank notes of the analogous cash principle, why not treat it as a nullity, by showing that the bank was actually, though not ostensibly insolvent at the time of the transaction. It is no answer that the note of an unbroken bank may be instantly converted into coin by presenting it at the counter. To do that may require a journey from Boston to New Orleans, or between places still further apart, and the bank may have stopped in the meantime, or it may stop at the instant of presentation when situated where the holder resides. And it may do so when it is not insolvent at all, but perfectly able eventually to pay the last shilling. This distinction between previous and subsequent failure evinced by stopping before the time of the transaction or after it is an arbitrary and impracticable one. To such a payment we must apply the cash principle entire, or we must treat it as a transfer of negotiable paper, imposing on the transferee no more than the ordinary mercantile responsibility in regard to presentation and notice of dishonor. There is no middle ground.

[ocr errors][merged small]

but in neither case has the party received what in the contemplation of both parties he was entitled to receive, if the contract was to pay a certain sum. In neither case has he received money or its representative. The sum contracted to be paid has not been paid in money or anything which [369] by usage passes as money, or which was entitled at the time to represent it; and the party has therefore failed to pay what he contracted to pay. Counterfeit coin may contain a portion of good metal and thus have some value, but this would not make it a good medium of payment. Entire worthlessness, or not, is not, therefore, the criterion." 1 [370] A return of such paper by the receiver is required as a condition of the right to recover from the payer; and the necessity of returning it arises from the same considerations in the case of counterfeit money, to enable the party paying to secure

It is no more a bank note than a dead horse is a living one; and it is an elementary principle, that what has no existence cannot be the subject of a contract. But it cannot be said that the genuine note of an insolvent bank has not an actual and a legitimate existence, though it be little worth; or that the receiver of it has not got the thing he expected. It ceases not to be genuine by the bank's insolvency; its legal obligation as a contract is undissolved, and it remains a promise to pay, though the promisor's ability to perform it be impaired or destroyed. . . . The difference between forgery and insolvency in relation to a bank note is as distinctly marked as the difference between title and quality in relation to the sale of a chattel.

"What then becomes of the boasted principle that a man shall not have parted with his property until he shall have had value, or rather what he expected for it? Like many others of the same school, it would be too refined for our times, even did a semblance of justice lie at the root of it. But nothing de

vised by human sagacity can do equal and exact justice in the apprehension of all men. The best that can be done, in any case, is no more than an approximation to it; and when the incidental risks of a business are so disposed of as to consist with the general convenience, no injustice will in the end be done to those by whom they are borne. Commerce is a system of dealing in which risk, as well as labor and capital, is to be compensated. But nothing can be more exactly balanced than the equities of parties to a payment in regard to the risk of the medium when its worthlessness was unsuspected by either of them. The difference between them is not the tithe of a hair or any other infinitesimal quantity that can be imagined; and in such a case the common law allows a loss from mutual mistake to rest where it has fallen, rather than to remove it from the shoulders of one innocent man to the shoulders of another equally so." 1 Fogg v. Sawyer, 9 N. H. 365; Frontier Bank v. Morse, 22 Me. 88; Magee v. Carmack, 13 Ill. 289.

himself with prior parties. But whether the rule requiring return within a reasonable time is confined to cases in which the payer has recourse does not appear to be decided. If the failure occurred while he was the owner of the bills he has no recourse; and if they are not returned why may not the party receiving and retaining them be charged with their value and the recovery be limited to the depreciation?1

225. Payment by note, bill or check. A creditor may receive anything of value as payment.? A debtor, by agreement with his creditor, may pay his contemporaneous or antecedent debt in a note or bill against a third person; but there must be a mutual agreement that it shall be transferred and received as final satisfaction without recourse or condition of being productive. Where goods are sold for a particular [371] note it is an exchange or barter, and the note has the effect of payment. And it has been held that when the note of a third person is taken without recourse, by indorsement or otherwise, for goods sold at the time, the presumption is it is taken in payment. There is no dissent from the proposition

1 Townsends v. Bank of Racine, 7 Wis. 185; Ontario Bank v. Light body, 13 Wend. 104.

In Magee v. Carmack, 13 Ill. 289, the court remark as to the question of what is a reasonable time: "When from the nature of the subject a general rule can be applied to all cases, then what constitutes reasonable notice may be a question of law for the court, as notice to the indorser of a bill or note. But when, as in this case, the question of what would constitute a reasonable time must depend upon the peculiar circumstances of each case, and cannot reasonably be subjected to any general rule, then it is a question of fact for the jury to be determined from all the circumstances."

2 Louden v. Birt, 4 Ind. 566; Reed v. Bartlett, 19 Pick. 273; Tilford v. Roberts, 8 Ind. 254.

3 St. John v. Purdy, 1 Sandf. 9; New York State Bank v. Fletcher, 5

Wend. 85; Conkling v. King, 10 N. Y. 440, affirming 10 Barb. 372; Roberts v. Fisher, 53 Barb. 69; Wright v. First Crockery Ware Co., 1 N. H. 281 ; Jaffrey v. Cornish, 10 id. 505; Elliot v. Sleeper, 2 id. 527; Randlet v. Herren, 20 id. 102; Brewer v. Branch Bank, 24 Ala. 440; Hutchins v. Olcutt, 4 Vt. 549; Hart v. Boller, 15 S. & R. 162; Citizens' Bank v. Carson, 32 Mo. 191; Smith v. Owens, 21 Cal. 11; Graves v. Friend, 5 Sandf. 568.

4 Ferdon v. Jones, 2 E. D. Smith, 106; Whitbeck v. Van Ness, 11 Johns. 409; Breed v. Cook, 15 id. 241; Rew v. Barber, 3 Cow. 272.

5 Hall v. Stevens, 116 N. Y. 201, reversing 40 Hun, 578; Gibson v. Tobey, 46 N. Y. 637; Corbit v. Bank of Smyrna, 2 Harr. (Del.) 235, 259; Torry v. Hadley, 27 Barb. 192; Whitbeck v. Van Ness, 11 Johns. 409; Noel v. Murray, 13 N. Y. 167; Rew v. Barber, 3 Cow. 272; Breed v. Cook, 15 Johns. 241; Bank of England v. Newman,

« 이전계속 »