페이지 이미지
PDF
ePub

Opinion of the Court.

up to the classification which he made of the cases coming within the first class, said:

"When one in business sold property with which the buyer might set up a rival business it was certainly reasonable that the seller should be able to restrain the buyer from doing him an injury which, but for the sale, the buyer would be unable to inflict."

It would be equally reasonable that the buyer should be able to restrain himself from using the property in any other way than setting up a rival business, so as to do the seller an injury which but for the sale he would be unable to inflict. But whether or not the system of contracts involved here comes within said fourth subclass, they are certainly covered by the language used by Judge Taft to take in any possible omissions from the classification he made. In each contract the restraining agreement is ancillary or collateral to the main purpose of a lawful contract, to wit, a sale of the medicine, [382] and, according to complainant's claim, it is necessary to protect him from an unjust use of the legitimate fruits of the contract by the purchaser. I therefore conclude that the system of contracts involved herein belongs to the first class, and that its validity depends solely upon its reasonableness. Is it reasonable, then, that complainant should have the right to put in force the system of contracts involved herein and obtain from his vendees and subvendees restraining agreements from the vendees, as to whom and at prices at which they shall resell, and from the subvendees as to the prices at which they shall resell? A question arises here as to the party on whom lies the burden as to the reasonableness. Is it on complainant to show that the restraint in question is reasonable, or is it on defendant to show that it is unreasonable?

Judge Simonton, in Hulse v. Bonsack Machine Co., supra,

says:

"This is not literally an agreement in restraint of trade. tI is simply a contract which by analogy can be likened to one, and the analogy should not be pushed beyond the reason for it. There is no presumption that such a contract is void. The presumption is in favor of the competency of the parties to make the contract and the burden is upon the party who alleges that it is unreasonable or against public policy."

Opinion of the Court.

On the other hand, Beach on Contracts, vol. 2, § 1562, says:

"Many authorities declare in substance that all restraints are presumed to be bad, but, if the circumstances are set forth, that presumption may be excluded, and the court judges of these circumstances whether the contract be void or not,"

I do not find it essential in this case to locate the burden, as I hold that under the allegations of the bill, which are admitted by the demurrer, said system of contracts as applied to complainant's medicine is reasonable. The circumstances which lead me to this conclusion are these: That complainant's vendees and subvendees should be so restrained is advantageous to complainant's business. It would be an injury to it from them not to be so restrained. Exactly how it is so advantaged and how it would be injured by a removal of the restraint has not been developed in the argument; and I do not feel sufficiently advised as to such matters to say as to this. It would seem that the existence of such a system of contracts in relation to complainant's medicine would tend to prevent demoralization in the trade therein through competition amongst his vendees and subvendees, and enable him to maintain the prices for his medicine. But, however this may be, it is alleged in the bill that before complainant established and put said system in force the "cut rate" or "cut price" system had resulted in much confusion, trouble, and damage to complainant's business, and had injuriously affected the reputation and depleted the sale of his medicine, and that it was established and put in force to protect his trade, custom, and business, and the manufacture and sale of his medicine; that it prevents cutting of prices and demoralization of trade both wholesale and retail, greatly benefits him by increasing the sales of and demand for his medicine, and is of great value to him in his business; and that it has been of great benefit and advantage to him and his business, and has increased his [383] trade and business. It is further alleged that the prices which he and his vendees and subvendees get for his medicine are reasonable. These allegations must be accepted as true. The vendees and subvendees would not have the opportunity to sell his medicine

Opinion of the Court.

if he did not make and sell it. He thus brings trade to them. By fixing a uniform price on his medicine on sales by himself to the wholesalers, on sales by wholesalers to retailers, and by retailers to consumers, all purchasers, wholesalers, retailers, and consumers are treated alike, the large wholesalers have no advantage over the small ones, nor the large retailers over the small ones. All sellers and all consumers are treated alike. Complainant creates the demand for the medicine, as he alone advertises it. And, finally, complainant could accomplish the very same result by a different system, against which no legal complaint could be made. This would be by a system of agencies. Though the nature of complainant's medicine; i. e., its being an article made under a secret process, may not, without more, determine the validity of the system of contracts in question, it cannot be said that it does not add to the reasonableness of said system as applied to it. Complainant not only owns it and makes it, but no one else can make it, and if they could they could not sell it under his trade-mark and dress.

How, then, does the matter stand upon authority? The whole trend of authority is favorable to the validity of the system. The sweeping principle which has taken form in Judge Taft's five classes and in the general statement to cover any omissions therefrom upholds it. But there are a number of decisions more directly in point. They are as follows, to wit: Elliman v. Carrington (1901), 2 Ch. 275, 84 L. T. (N. S.) 853; Garst v. Harris, 177 Mass. 72, 58 N. E. 174; Walsh v. Dwight (Sup.) 58 N. Y. Supp 91; Park & Sons Co. v. National Wholesale Druggists, 175 N. Y. 1, 67 N. E. 136, 62 L. R. A. 632, 96 Am. St. Rep. 578; Whitwell v. Tobacco Co. 125 Fed. 454, 60 C. C. A. 290, 64 L. R. A. 689.

In Elliman v. Carrington, the plaintiffs were manufacturers of Elliman's Royal Embrocation for horses and cattle and Elliman's Universal Embrocation for human beings. They sold it to the defendants, who bought wholesale to sell to others at retail. The latter agreed not to sell below certain prices and not to sell to others unless they agreed not to sell below certain prices. They broke the latter part of the agree

Opinion of the Court.

ment which was the occasion of the suit. It was held that the agreement was valid. Mr. Justice Kekewich said:

"The [plaintiffs] are not bound to sell the embrocation at all; they are not bound to manufacture it. They are at liberty to do so as they please, and when they have manufactured it, they are at liberty to sell it at whatever price they choose to fix, it may be a prohibitive one or it may be such a small price that they cannot make any profit out of it. That is entirely for their consideration. There are no goods which the owner thereof may not lawfully retain or sell at such price as he pleases."

Again he says:

Why should not Elliman's Sons & Co. be at liberty to fix the price in that way? Nobody has argued and it could not possibly be argued that they are not at liberty to fix the price in the first sale to Carrington & Son. Why [384] should they not be at liberty to make the further bargain with Carrington & Son that they shall not sell it below a certain price? It is said that the contract is in restraint of trade. In one sense it is, but it is just as much and no more in restraint of trade for Elliman's Sons & Co. to say that they will not sell at all. It seems to me, to say the least, that what is restraint of trade as regards Carrington & Son is really the liberty of trade as regards Elliman's Sons & Co. The cases which have been cited are well-known authorities expounding a great principle, and showing what exceptions there are to that principle. But this case seems to me not to fall within any principle or exception. I do not think that it is touched by the authorities at all. It is merely a question of whether a man is entitled when he is selling his own goods to make a bargain as to the use to be made of them by the purchaser. It is said that the contract is against public policy, but that phrase merely embodies for the present purpose the great principle of restraint of trade, and to say that it is to prevent Elliman's Sons & Co. from exercising their own discretion, seems to me to be applying a well-settled principle of law to facts to which it cannot have any possible application.”

It is to be noted that though the article which was sold in this case was probably made under a secret process, no emphasis was laid upon the fact. The reasoning applies equally well to any article which one may own, whether he made it or not, and which he sells for purpose of resale.

In Garst v. Harris, the plaintiff sold Phenyo-Caffein, a proprietary medicine, to defendant, who agreed not to sell it below a stipulated price, and a certain sum was agreed on as liquidated damages. The action was brought for a breach of this agreement to recover said sum. It was held that the agreement was valid.

**

Holmes, C. J., said:

"It is said that the contract was unlawful as in restraint of trade. * When, as here, there is a secret composition, which the defendant presumably would have no chance to sell at a profit'at all, but for the plaintiff's permission, a limit to the license, in the form of a restriction of the price at which he may sell, is proper enough."

Opinion of the Court.

It is true that the fact that the article sold was a secret composition was emphasized. But the reasoning used was equally applicable to any other article; as to any other article sold the purchaser would not have had any chance to sell that particular article, however it may have been as to other articles of the same kind, at a profit at all, but by the. seller's permission.

Point is made as to these two cases that in each but a single contract was involved, and not a system of contracts as here. That is true, but no doubt there was a system of contracts in each of those cases as here. A single contract; i. e., a contract with a single purchaser, would hardly have been of any value to the seller. It was only by a system of contracts; i. e., a contract with every purchaser, that he could hope to accomplish anything. This must have been had in view by the court, as no point was made of the fact that there was but a single contract involved, and the reasoning was applicable to a system.

In Walsh v. Dwight, the defendants were manufacturers and sellers of saleratus and soda, articles in common use and capable of being manufactured by any one, which was known on the market as" Dwight's Cow Brand Saleratus and Soda." They sold these articles to job- [385] bers under contracts, whereby the latter, in consideration of a certain discount, agreed not to resell same or any other saleratus or soda at less than certain prices. The plaintiffs were rival manufacturers of saleratus and soda, and the suit was to recover damages sustained by them because of defendant's system of contracts. It was assumed that plaintiff's had a right of action if the system of contracts was invalid and the disposition of the case was made to turn on its validity. It was held to be valid. Judge Ingraham said:

"It is difficult to see upon what ground it can be claimed that such a contract is illegal. That the defendants would have the right to establish agencies for the sale of their goods, or to employ others to sell them, at such prices as the defendants should designate, cannot be disputed. Nor can it be that a manufacturer of merchandise cannot agree to sell to others upon condition that the vendee, in selling at retail, should charge a specified price for the goods sold, or should sell only the manufactured product of the manufacturer. If a dealer in articles of this kind, for his own advantage, agrees to confine his business to a particular line of goods, or agrees with the manufacturer to charge a particular price for the articles which he sells in his busi

« 이전계속 »